Ever since Max Weber proposed his ‘Protestant ethic’ hypothesis in 1904-05, social scientists have questioned the role that religion plays in either enhancing or retarding economic growth. The biggest problem for such inquiries was a lack of available data and analytical frameworks for connecting the two. This is no longer true. In the last two decades, social scientists have made significant contributions to our understanding of how religion affects growth.
Figure 1 Michelangelo: The Creation of Adam
Religion and the elements of the macroeconomic production function
Standard growth models consider macroeconomic production functions containing several inputs that can affect economic growth. These inputs include physical capital, human capital, population/labour, and total factor productivity (TFP). In a recent survey article (Becker et al. 2024), we argue that each of these inputs can be augmented or impaired by religion. These connections emerge because religious beliefs, religious practice, religious institutions, and religious doctrine can shape individual preferences, societal norms, and economic institutions. We use the various elements of the macroeconomic production function as proximate determinants in a unifying framework to study religion as one of the deeper, more fundamental determinants of growth.
The availability of new data, advances in computing, and new econometric techniques have greatly improved our capacity to test how various aspects of religion affect each of these growth inputs in rich and poor countries, historically and in the present (see also Becker et al. 2020, 2021). Although few studies seek to understand the broader connections between religion and growth (a well-known exception being the work of Barro and McCleary 2003; see also McCleary and Barro 2019), this literature has flourished to the point that we can begin to generalise by combining and conceptually organising the results of different, often disconnected studies into a unifying framework.
Physical capital
One of the most well-known growth inputs is physical capital, and one of Weber’s central arguments was that certain ‘Protestant traits’ – such as thrift and saving – were key to Protestant capital accumulation. Several studies suggest that there are indeed differences across religious faiths in these and other economically important cultural beliefs. Yet, the recent literature is rather mixed as to whether this is a specific value that some religions hold, or whether it only arises in certain contexts (e.g. Guiso et al. 2003, Kersting et al. 2020).
Religion also affects financial development, itself a key input into physical capital accumulation. Examples include restrictions on taking interest (Rubin 2011a, 2011b), religious law on commercial activity (Kuran 2011, Kuran and Rubin 2018a, 2018b), and religious institutions that direct capital away from more productive enterprises (Kuran 2023). All of these have been alleged to set some societies on very different growth trajectories than others.
Human capital
Human capital has long been affected by religion and religious beliefs. Several authors have studied the effect of Islamic education on science (Chaney 2023), labour markets (Saleh 2015), and literacy (Chaudhary and Rubin 2011). Others have studied the crowding-out effect that religious education has on secular education, and its subsequent effects on industrialisation (see e.g. Squicciarini 2020, Bénabou et al. 2022, Liang 2010, Arold et al. 2022a, 2022b). Others have focused on the human capital consequences of Christian missionary activity (e.g. Gallego and Woodberry 2010, Bai and Kung 2015, Valencia Caicedo 2019).
Two faiths have been shown to be positively related to educational outcomes associated with economic growth: Judaism and Protestantism. Jews specialised in high human capital professions beginning in the centuries following the destruction of the Second Temple in Jerusalem (Botticini and Eckstein 2005, 2007), and this human capital advantage has largely persisted to the present day (with some exceptions such as Ultra-Orthodox Jews, e.g. Berman 2000).
Protestants had a cultural inclination favouring human capital accumulation from their beginnings. Martin Luther wanted his flock to know how to read so they could study the bible. This had spillovers into economically relevant human capital that gave Protestants an advantage in the economic development of the 19th century and beyond (Becker and Woessmann 2009).
Population and labour
Religion also impacts economic growth through the channels of population and labour. The most famous labour channel is Weber’s idea that Protestants developed a stronger work ethic than others to show that they were members of the ‘elect’, who were predestined to go to heaven. Although this thesis has captured the popular imagination, the findings are mixed regarding whether Protestants in fact have a superior work ethic (e.g. Andersen et al. 2017, Spenkuch 2017).
Religion can shape a society’s demographic patterns as well. This can affect economic growth by limiting the number of children families have (thus making more resources available for investment in their human capital, see Becker et al. 2010), by hastening or delaying a country’s demographic transition (Blanc 2023), or by affecting mortality (Becker and Woessmann 2018).
Figure 2 Conclave in the Sistine Chapel
Total factor productivity
A final mechanism through which religion affects growth is via its impact on the productive capacity of a society (TFP). There are several mechanisms through which religion affects productivity. One is religious belief. Religious prohibitions, especially of productive activities or technologies, can have a detrimental effect on productivity (Bénabou et al. 2022, Seror 2018, Coşgel et al. 2012). Likewise, religious tolerance can positively impact technology utilisation by opening opportunities to those who would not innovate otherwise (Cinnirella and Streb 2018, Hornung 2019).
Religion can likewise affect productivity via its effect on political economy. Religious rituals can affect productivity by shaping cultural norms and economic behaviour, as in the case of Ramadan fasting (Campante and Yanagizawa-Drott 2015) or Catholic saint day festivals in Mexico (Montero and Yang 2022). Where religion plays an important role in legitimating political rule, it is likely that religious authorities will participate in political bargaining (Rubin 2017). This can have all sorts of unintended consequences for economic growth, as the interests of religious authorities and the mechanisms of religious politics are not always aligned with prosperity (e.g. Chaney 2013, Bazzi et al. 2020). Intertwining religion and politics can also result in religious persecution, which can have negative consequences for long-run growth (Voigtländer and Voth 2012, Johnson and Koyama 2019, Miguel 2005).
Religion matters for growth in multiple ways
In both past and present, religion impinges on every input into the macroeconomic production function. Although many studies connecting religion and growth focus on narrow events, eras, and locations, the cumulative evidence from these studies is clear: religion matters for economic growth. How, when, and where it matters is context specific, but economists disregard religion at their peril.
References
Andersen, T B, J Bentzen, C-J Dalgaard and P Sharp (2017), “Pre-Reformation Roots of the Protestant Ethic”, Economic Journal 127(604): 1756–93.
Arold, B W, L Woessmann and L Zierow (2022a), “Can Schools Change Religious Attitudes? Evidence from German State Reforms of Compulsory Religious Education”, CESifo Working Paper 9504.
Arold, B W, L Woessmann and L Zierow (2022b), “Religious Education in School Affects Students’ Lives in the Long Run”, VoxEU.org, 3 March.
Bai, Y and J Kai-sing Kung (2015), “Diffusing Knowledge while Spreading God’s Message: Protestantism and Economic Prosperity in China, 1840–1920”, Journal of the European Economic Association 13(4): 669–98.
Barro, R J and R M McCleary (2003), “Religion and Economic Growth across Countries”, American Sociological Review 68(5): 760–81.
Bazzi, S, G Koehler-Derrick and B Marx (2020), “The Institutional Foundations of Religious Politics: Evidence from Indonesia”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 135(2): 845–911.
Becker, S O and L Woessmann (2018), “Social Cohesion, Religious Beliefs, and the Effect of Protestantism on Suicide”, Review of Economics and Statistics 100(3): 377–91.
Becker, S O, F Cinnirella and L Woessmann (2010), “The Trade-Off between Fertility and Education: Evidence from before the Demographic Transition”, Journal of Economic Growth 15(3): 177–204.
Becker, S O, J Rubin and L Woessmann (2020), “Recent Insights on the Role of Religion in Economic History”, VoxEU.org, 12 July.
Becker, S O, J Rubin and L Woessmann (2021), “Religion in Economic History: A Survey”, The Handbook of Historical Economics, London: Academic Press, 585–639.
Becker, S O, J Rubin and L Woessmann (2024), “Religion and Growth”, Journal of Economic Literature 62(3): 1094–142.
Becker, S O and L Woessmann (2009), “Was Weber Wrong? A Human Capital Theory of Protestant Economic History”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(2): 531–96.
Bénabou, R, D Ticchi and A Vindigni (2022), “Forbidden Fruits: The Political Economy of Science, Religion, and Growth”, Review of Economic Studies 89(4): 1785–832.
Berman, E (2000), “Sect, Subsidy, and Sacrifice: An Economist’s View of Ultra-Orthodox Jews”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3): 905–53.
Blanc, G (2023), “The Cultural Origins of the Demographic Transition in France”, Working Paper.
Botticini, M and Z Eckstein (2005), “Jewish Occupational Selection: Education, Restrictions, or Minorities?”, Journal of Economic History 65(4): 922–48.
Botticini, M and Z Eckstein (2007), “From Farmers to Merchants, Conversions and Diaspora: Human Capital and Jewish History”, Journal of the European Economic Association 5(5): 885–926.
Campante, F and D Yanagizawa-Drott (2015), “Does Religion Affect Economic Growth and Happiness? Evidence from Ramadan”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 130(2): 615–58.
Chaney, E (2013), “Revolt on the Nile: Economic Shocks, Religion, and Political Power”, Econometrica 81(5): 2033–53.
Chaney, E (2023), “Religion and the Rise and Fall of Islamic Science”, Working Paper.
Chaudhary, L and J Rubin (2011), “Reading, Writing, and Religion: Institutions and Human Capital Formation”, Journal of Comparative Economics 39(1): 17–33.
Cinnirella, F and J Streb (2018), “Religious Tolerance as Engine of Innovation”, CESifo Working Paper 6797.
Coşgel, M M, T J Miceli and J Rubin (2012), “The Political Economy of Mass Printing: Legitimacy, Revolt, and Technology Change in the Ottoman Empire”, Journal of Comparative Economics 40(3): 357–71.
Gallego, F A and R Woodberry (2010), “Christian Missionaries and Education in Former African Colonies: How Competition Mattered”, Journal of African Economics 19(3): 294–329.
Guiso, L, P Sapienza and L Zingales (2003), “People’s Opium? Religion and Economic Attitudes”, Journal of Monetary Economics 50(1): 225–82.
Hornung, E (2019), “Diasporas, Diversity, and Economic Activity: Evidence from 18th-century Berlin”, Explorations in Economic History 73: 101261.
Johnson, N D and M Koyama (2019), Persecution and Toleration: The Long Road to Religious Freedom, Cambridge University Press.
Kersting, F, I Wohnsiedler and N Wolf (2020), “Weber Revisited: The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Nationalism”, Journal of Economic History 80(3): 710–45.
Kuran, T (2011), The Long Divergence: How Islamic Law Held Back the Middle East, Princeton University Press.
Kuran, T and J Rubin (2018a), “The Financial Power of the Powerless: Socio-Economic Status and Interest Rates under Weak Rule of Law”, Economic Journal 128(609): 758–96.
Kuran, T and J Rubin (2018b), “The Financial Power of the Powerless: Evidence from Ottoman Istanbul”, VoxEU.org, 28 April.
Kuran, T (2023), Freedoms Delayed: Political Legacies of Islamic Law in the Middle East, Cambridge University Press.
Liang, M-Y (2010), “Confucianism and the East Asian Miracle”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2(3): 206–34.
McCleary, R M and R J Barro (2019), The Wealth of Religions: The Political Economy of Believing and Belonging, Princeton University Press.
Miguel, E (2005), “Poverty and Witch Killing”, Review of Economic Studies 72(4): 1153–72.
Montero, E and D Yang (2022), “Religious Festivals and Economic Development: Evidence from the Timing of Mexican Saint Day Festivals”, American Economic Review 112(10): 3176–214.
Rubin, J (2011a), “Institutions, the Rise of Commerce, and the Persistence of Laws: Interest Restrictions in Islam and Christianity”, Economic Journal 121(557): 1310–339.
Rubin, J (2011b), “Institutions, Religion, and the Rise of Europe vis-à-vis the Middle East: A Long-run Reversal of Fortunes”, VoxEU.org, 22 December.
Rubin, J (2017), Rulers, Religion, and Riches: Why the West Got Rich and the Middle East Did Not, Cambridge University Press.
Saleh, M (2015), “The Reluctant Transformation: State Industrialization, Religion, and Human Capital in Nineteenth-Century Egypt”, Journal of Economic History 75(1): 65–94.
Seror, A (2018), “A Theory on the Evolution of Religious Norms and Economic Prohibition”, Journal of Development Economics 134: 416–27.
Spenkuch, J L (2017), “Religion and Work: Micro Evidence from Contemporary Germany”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 135: 193–214.
Squicciarini, M (2020), “Devotion and Development: Religiosity, Education, and Economic Progress in 19th-Century France”, American Economic Review 110(11): 3454–91.
Valencia Caicedo, F (2019), “The Mission: Human Capital Transmission, Economic Persistence, and Culture in South America”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 134(1): 507–56.
Voigtländer, N and H-J Voth (2012), “Persecution Perpetuated: The Medieval Origins of Anti-Semitic Violence in Nazi Germany”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 127(3): 1339–92.
Weber, M (1904–5), The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, London: Routledge Classics.